Little value creation, articulation and propagating forces: A hypothesis for the Mexican manufacturing sector
Keywords:
Industrialization, Technological change, Industrial policy, Trade, Latin AmericaAbstract
This paper evaluates the impact of Mexican trade and productive integration processes during the last 20 years. It finds evidence that growing per capita income in Mexico is directly related to its “trade opening”, but is inversely related to the growth of its manufacturing export industry. Specifically, for each point of growth in “trade opening” (as a proportion of GDP) per capita income grew by 0.22%; while each point of increase in the share of industrial exports reduced income per person by 0.09%. To explain this apparent contradiction between the positive effect of “trade opening” and the negative impact of productive manufacturing specialization, we examined the characteristics of Mexico’s industry. Results show that although Mexico’s export-led industrialization successfully adapted to the world market and transformed its productive, business, organizational and technological structure, it did not translate into adequate macroeconomic benefits due to the absence of strong value dissemination forces over the rest of the economy. In this sense, poor internal linkages in the maquila industry, its high propensity to import, and its limited value added generation, among other elements, led the Mexican industry to operate as an export enclave. In those circumstances, manufacturing does not generates positive externalities nor articulations, nor strong disseminations that increase and multiplies value in other sectors of industry, thus limiting expansion effects and restraining or even reducing–under some specific circumstances–per capita income growth.
Downloads
References
Alonso, J., Carrillo, J., & Contreras, O. (2002). Enero-Junio. Aprendizaje tecnológico en las maquiladoras del norte de México. En Frontera Norte, 14(27), 43–82.
BID (2001). Competitividad, el motor del crecimiento: progreso económico social en América latina. Informe 2001. Washington, DC: BID, p.292.
Buitelaar, R., Padilla, R., & Urrutia, R. (1999). Abril. Industria maquiladora y cambio técnico. Revista CEPAL, 67, 133–152.
Cepal (2003). Anuario Estadístico de América latina y el Caribe, 2002. Santiago de Chile: Cepal.
Cepal (2003a). Panorama de la inserción internacional de América latina y el Caribe, 2001-2002. Santiago de Chile: Cepal.
Dollar, D.(1992). April. Outward-oriented developing countries really do grow more rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs. 1976-85. Economic Development and Cultural Change.
Dollar, D. and A. Kraay (2001). Trade, growth, and poverty. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper.
Dollar, D. y A. Kraay (2003). Institutions, trade, and growth: Revisiting the evidence. World Bank Research.
Edwards, S. (1992). Trade orientation, distortions, and growth in developing countries. Journal of Development Economics, 39(1), 31–57.
Frankel, J., & Romer, D. (1999). June. Does trade cause growth? The American Economic Review, 379–399.
Graham, F. D. (1923 February). Some aspects of protection further considered. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 199–227.
Krugman, P.(comp.)(1991). Una política comercial estratégica para la nueva economía internacional, México, DF: FCE, 303 pp.
Matsuyama,K.(1992). December.Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 58, New York, Academic Press.
Mortimore, M., Vergara, S. and J. Katz (2001). La competitividad internacional y el desarrollo nacional: implicancias para la política de IDE en América Latina. CEPAL, Serie Desarrollo Productivo, 107.
Reinert, E. (2002). Junio. El rol de la tecnología en la creación de países ricos y pobres: el subdesarrollo en un sistema schumpeteriano. Cuadernos de Difusión, 12. Lima: Escuela de Administración de Negocios para Graduados, ESAN,
pp. 7-36.
Roca, S. and L. Simabuko (1999). Diciembre. Value and quality creation: natural resources, industrialization and standards of living in Cuadernos de Difusión, 9-10. Lima: Escuela de Administración de Negocios para Graduados, ESAN, pp. 69-123.
Roca, S., y L. Simabuko (2004) Natural Resources, industrialization and fluctuating standards of living in Peru, 1950-97: A case study of activity-specific economic growth, in Reinert, S. Erik (2004) Globalization, Economic Development and
Inequality, Edward Elgar, 339 pp.
Romer, Paul (1990). Endogenous technological change, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No 5, The University of Chicago Press.
Ros, J. (2001). Abril. Política industrial, ventajas comparativas y crecimiento. Revista de la Cepal, 73, 129–148.
Sachs, J. and A. Warner (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (1), 1-118.
Sachs, J. y A. Warner (1995a). Natural resource abundance and economic growth. Working Paper 5398, NBER.
Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997). I just ran two million regressions. American Economic Review, 87(1)
Unctad (2001). Informe sobre las inversiones en el mundo, 2001. Objetivo: fomentar las vinculaciones. Panorama general. Nueva York y Ginebra: Naciones Unidas, pp.81
Downloads
Published
How to Cite
Issue
Section
License
Copyright (c) 2021 Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License.